Technocratic economic governance is a much more social and political process than many advocates of economic rules-based policy acknowledge – British…

Posted: April 11, 2022 at 6:15 am

Analysing UK macroeconomic policy rules and their operation unearths numerous dimensions of the politics of technocratic fiscal policy-making, writes Ben Clift. Firstly, policy rules are marshalled for partisan purposes. Secondly, a politics of economic ideas surrounds the invention, revision, and interpretation of fiscal rules. Thirdly, technocratic economic governance entails selecting methodological approaches necessarily built on particular political economic assumptions. Finally, politicians cook the books to present their economic record favourably against fiscal yardsticks,thus there is an inevitable politics of technocratic economic governance.

Technocratic governance has become a pervasive feature of economic management in advanced democracies. My research explores a yawning gap between the theory and the practice of technocratic economic governance. The real world of fiscal rules is more political and social than conventional accounts admit. In the late 20th and early 21st centuries, governments introduced fiscal policy rules to reassure electorates and financial markets that they were sound custodians of the public finances. Such depoliticisation supposedly took fiscal policy away from fractious parliamentary politics, moving it towards the realms of technical administration.

Some academic work discusses fiscal rules as if they are sacrosanct and unchanging. Yet state managers exhibit powerful desires to escape these constraints, with fiscal rules repeatedly flouted and frequently changed. Economic policymakers have an apparent compulsion to hem themselves in, yet this is tethered to a more powerful impulse to escape these self-imposed shackles. Analysing the creation, revision, and transgression of these rules illustrates how they are embedded in distinctive, yet overlapping, forms of politics.

The (partisan) politics of economic ideas

Despite their apolitical appearance, fiscal rules are frequently marshalled for partisan purposes that reveal the particular economic ideas surrounding their invention, revision, and interpretation. Following its election in 1997, the Labour government introduced fiscal rules to bolster the partys economic credibility. Chancellor Gordon Brown adopted a Golden Rule specifying that, over the business cycle, the government would borrow only to invest, not to fund current spending.

The aim was to demonstrate Labours fiscal prudence, while simultaneously addressing historical UK under-investment. Indeed, they were underpinned by a particular vision of political economy: Paul Romers new growth agenda. This emphasised a wide-ranging role for the state in providing technological, infrastructural, and human capital investment. They therefore embodied a critique of prior Conservative economic management, which had engineered a dramatic reduction in public investment over the preceding decades.

Although Labours rules supposedly enshrined fiscal prudence, their observance was at times only sustained by moving the goalposts. Nevertheless, iron Chancellor Browns construction of economic credibility appeared to pay dividends, enabling Labour government to boost health and education spending without increasing borrowing costs. The Global Financial Crisis and the arrival in 2010 of the Coalition and Conservative governments, upended this positive impression. Rebranding the crash Labours debt crisis, the Conservatives claimed Labours profligate mismanagement left the country facing a Greek-style crisis. Cameron and Osborne pivoted to an austerity-centric economic orthodoxy, urging Britain to live within its means. Harsh public spending cuts ensued; new tougher fiscal rules were introduced. The newly created Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR) sought to ensure prudence through independent fiscal oversight.

The Coalitions economic analysis made bold assumptions about debts adverse effects on future growth, and accordingly prioritised spending cuts. This position reflected the expansionary fiscal contraction thesis, counterintuitively arguing that reducing public expenditure amidst a recession was necessary for restoring economic health. These ideas permeated George Osbornes tough new fiscal rules, endorsing the pursuit of a structural budget surplus and reducing public debt relative to GDP.

The politics of numbers and politics of method

Despite technocratic aspirations to move fiscal policy into a depoliticised administrative realm, rules-based fiscal policy remains enmeshed in a politics of numbers (statistical book-cooking to meet numerical targets), and a politics of economic method (manipulating parameters of economic models). Part of Chancellor Osbornes rationale for creating the OBR was an ostensible desire to curtail these political shenanigans by delegating fiscal oversight to an external expert institution. Here, Osborne was again critical of Labours record. In 2005, Brown had re-interpreted his fiscal rules, altering the economic cycles start from 1997 to 1999, despite much evidence suggesting otherwise. This change enabled Brown to claim his Golden Rule had been met.

For all Osbornes critique of Labour book-cooking, Conservative Chancellors were unrelenting in their own fiscal manipulations. The OBR consistently noted the scorecard artistry of Osbornes Treasury. Spending commitments were manoeuvred into following years (as with World Bank payments in 2013) in order that, within specified forecast periods, fiscal targets were notionally hit.

The OBR, its independent overseer status notwithstanding, was no less embedded in the politics of fiscal policy. Its creation by the Conservatives in opposition, and imbrication in partisan fiscal tussles over Labours alleged profligacy, gives the lie to outsourced, technocratic economic governance being apolitical. Furthermore, while its creation circumscribed the governmental politics of economic method, ruling out some of the old shenanigans (such as massaging trend growth rates), a politics of economic method persisted within the OBRs own fiscal modelling. This did not operate to portray UK fiscal policy systematically in a more or less favourable light, nevertheless OBR staff attest to the degree of judgement, intuition and tacit knowledge involved in conducting economic forecasting and oversight.

The OBR like other independent fiscal institutions must grapple with slippery, non-observable economic concepts that are very hard to gauge. Measures of potential output, the output gap (the degree of slack available in the economy) and potential productivity are integral to medium-term economic forecasting and the enactment of fiscal rules. No agreed approach exists for discerning these with practitioners acknowledging methodological choices can be somewhat arbitrary. Techniques can reflect differing and contestable views of the economy. A statistical filters approach one amongst many available alternatives for determining the output gap assumes, for example, that an economy tends promptly towards equilibrium, thus yielding a distinctive growth path. In this way, different understandings of the economy and policy underpin apparently technical choices. This reveals the persistent and consequential politics of economic method underlying fiscal rules regimes and technocratic fiscal governance.

Conclusion

Fiscal rules and their enactment reflect dominant but changeable ideas of sound fiscal policy and the influence of partisan political concerns. Governments frequently use rules regimes to participate in the social construction of economic credibility, often to denigrate opponents. They breach or change rules, or engage in book-cooking shenanigans to secure an observance of the rules that is somewhat illusory. Forecasting methods and techniques, whilst presentedin technical and formalistic manner, alsoconstitute keysiteswhere choices made can reflect different economic worldviews distilled in economic modelling assumptions. Far from taking the politics out of fiscal policy, the advent of fiscal rules and the OBR engenders new forms of contested fiscal politics and elite statecraft. This politics may be hidden, but remains burgeoningly present.

_____________________

Note: the above draws on the authors published work in British Politics.

About the Author

Ben Cliftis Professor of Political Economy at the University of Warwick.

Photo by micheile .com on Unsplash.

The rest is here:

Technocratic economic governance is a much more social and political process than many advocates of economic rules-based policy acknowledge - British...

Related Posts